Homothetic preferences

In consumer theory, a consumer's preferences are called homothetic if they can be represented by a utility function which is homogeneous of degree 1.[1]:146 For example, in an economy with two goods , homothetic preferences can be represented by an utility function that has the following property: for every :

In mathematics, a homothetic function is a monotonic transformation of a function which is homogeneous;[2] however, since ordinal utility functions are only defined up to a monotonic transformation, there is little distinction between the two concepts in consumer theory.[1]:147

In a model where competitive consumers optimize homothetic utility functions subject to a budget constraint, the ratios of goods demanded by consumers will depend only on relative prices, not on income or scale. This translates to a linear expansion path in wealth: the slope of indifference curves is constant along rays beginning at the origin.[1]:482

Furthermore, the indirect utility function can be written as a linear function of the wealth :

which is a special case of the Gorman polar form. Hence, if all consumers have (the same) homothetic preferences, the aggregate demand can be calculated by considering a single "representative consumer" who has the same preferences and the same aggregate income.[1]:152–154

Examples

Utility functions having constant elasticity of substitution (CES) are homothetic. They can be represented by a utility function such as:

This function is homogeneous of degree 1:

Linear utilities, Leontief utilities and Cobb–Douglas utilities are special cases of CES functions and thus are also homothetic.

On the other hand, quasilinear utilities are, in general, not homothetic. E.g, the function cannot be represented as a homogeneous function.

Intratemporally vs. intertemporally homothetic preferences

Intratemporally homothetic preferences means that, in the same time period, consumers with different incomes but facing the same prices will demand goods in the same proportions.

Intertemporally homothetic preferences means that, across time periods, rich and poor decision makers are equally averse to proportional fluctuations in consumption.

Models of modern macroeconomics and public finance often assume the constant-relative-risk-aversion form for within period utility (also called the power utility or isoelastic utility). The reason is that, in combination with additivity over time, this gives homothetic intertemporal preferences and this homotheticity is of considerable analytic convenience (for example, it allows for the analysis of steady states in growth models). These assumptions imply that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, and its inverse, the coefficient of (risk) aversion, are constant. This may have significant implications, for example when evaluating the costs of business cycles or evaluating a policy change in a dynamic general equilibrium model with heterogeneous agents.

See also

References

  1. 1 2 3 4 Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0393957357.
  2. Simon, Carl and Lawrence Blume. Mathematics for Economists (Student ed.). Viva Norton. p. 500. ISBN 978-81-309-1600-2.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the 9/15/2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.