List of liberal theorists
Individual contributors to classical liberalism and political liberalism are associated with philosophers of the Enlightenment. Liberalism as a specifically named ideology begins in the late 18th century as a movement towards self-government and away from aristocracy. It included the ideas of self-determination, the primacy of the individual and the nation, as opposed to the state and religion, as being the fundamental units of law, politics and economy.
Since then liberalism has broadened to include a wide range of approaches from Americans Ronald Dworkin, Richard Rorty, John Rawls and Francis Fukuyama as well as the Indian Amartya Sen and the Peruvian Hernando de Soto. Some of these people moved away from liberalism, while others espoused other ideologies before turning to liberalism. There are many different views of what constitutes liberalism, and some liberals would feel that some of the people on this list were not true liberals. It is intended to be suggestive rather than exhaustive. Theorists whose ideas were mainly typical for one country should be listed in that country's section of liberalism worldwide. Generally only thinkers are listed, politicians are only listed when they, beside their active political work, also made substantial contributions to liberal theory.
Classical contributors to liberalism
Aristotle
Aristotle (Athens, 384 BC – 322 BC) is revered among political theorists for his seminal work Politics. He made invaluable contributions to liberal theory through his observations on different forms of government and the nature of man.
He begins with the idea that the best government provides an active and "happy" life for its people. Aristotle then considers six forms of government: Monarchy, Aristocracy, and Polity on one side as 'good' forms of government, and Tyranny, Oligarchy, and Democracy as 'bad' forms. Considering each in turn, Aristotle rejects Monarchy as infantilizing of citizens, Oligarchy as too profit-motivated, Tyranny as against the will of the people, Democracy as serving only to the poor, and Aristocracy (known today as Meritocracy) as ideal but ultimately impossible. Aristotle finally concludes that a polity—a combination between democracy and oligarchy, where most can vote but must choose among the rich and virtuous for governors—is the best compromise between idealism and realism.
In addition, Aristotle was a firm supporter of private property. He refuted Plato's argument for a collectivist society in which family and property are held in common: Aristotle makes the argument that when one's own son or land is rightfully one's own, one puts much more effort into cultivating that item, to the ultimate betterment of society. He references barbarian tribes of his time in which property was held in common, and the laziest of the bunch would always take away large amounts of food grown by the most diligent.
"Humanism"
Niccolò Machiavelli
Niccolò Machiavelli (Florence, 1469–1527), best known for his Il Principe was the founder of realist political philosophy, advocated republican government, citizen armies, division of power, protection of personal property, and restraint of government expenditure as being necessary to the liberties of a republic. He wrote extensively on the need for individual initiative – virtu – as an essential characteristic of stable government. He argued that liberty was the central good which government should protect, and that "good people" would make good laws, whereas people who had lost their virtue could maintain their liberties only with difficulty. His Discourses on Livy outlined realism as the central idea of political study and favored "Republics" over "Principalities".
Anti-statist liberals consider Machiavelli's distrust as his main message, noting his call for a strong state under a strong leader, who should use any means to establish his position, whereas liberalism is an ideology of individual freedom and voluntary choices.
- Contributing literature:
- Il Principe, 1513 ([The Prince]], )
- Discorsi sopra la prima deca di Tito Livio, 1512-1517 (Discourse on the First Decade of Titus Livius)
Desiderius Erasmus
Desiderius Erasmus (Netherlands, 1466–1536) was an advocate of the doctrine now known as humanism, critic of entrenched interests, irrationality and superstition. Erasmusian societies formed across Europe, to some extent in response to the turbulence of the Reformation. He dealt with the freedom of the will, a crucial point. In his De libero arbitrio diatribe sive collatio (1524), he analyzes with great cleverness and good humour the Lutheran exaggeration of the obvious limitations on human freedom.
- Contributing literature
- Stultitiae Laus, 1509 (The Praise of Folly, )
- De libero arbitrio diatribe sive collatio, 1524
Thomas Hobbes
Thomas Hobbes (England, 1588–1679) theorized that government is the result of individual actions and human traits, and that it was motivated primarily by "interest", a term which would become crucial in the development of a liberal theory of government and political economy, since it is the foundation of the idea that individuals can be self-governing and self-regulating. His work Leviathan, did not advocate this viewpoint, but instead that only a strong government could restrain unchecked interest: it did, however, advance a proto-liberal position in arguing for an inalienable "right of nature," the right to defend oneself, even against the state. Though it is problematic to classify Hobbes himself as a liberal, his work influenced Locke, Hamilton, Jefferson, Madison and many other later liberals, leading Strauss to identify Hobbes as the "father of liberalism".[1]
- Contributing literature:
- Leviathan, 1651 (Theologico-Political Treatise)
Baruch Spinoza
Baruch Spinoza (Netherlands, 1632–1677) is in his Tractatus Theologico-Politicus and Tractatus Politicus a proto-liberal defending the value of separation of church and state as well as forms of democracy. In the first mentioned book, Spinoza expresses an early criticism of religious intolerance and a defense of secular government. Spinoza was a thoroughgoing determinist who held that absolutely everything that happens occurs through the operation of necessity. For him, even human behaviour is fully determined, freedom being our capacity to know we are determined and to understand why we act as we do. So freedom is not the possibility to say "no" to what happens to us but the possibility to say "yes" and fully understand why things should necessarily happen that way.
- Contributing literature:
- Tractatus Theologico-Politicus, 1670 (Theologico-Political Treatise, )
- Tractatus Politicus, 1677 (Political Treatise)
From Locke to Mill
John Locke
John Locke's (England, 1632–1704) notion that a "government with the consent of the governed" and man's natural rights—life, liberty, and estate (property) as well on tolerance, as laid down in A letter concerning toleration and Two treatises of government —had an enormous influence on the development of liberalism. Developed a theory of property resting on the actions of individuals, rather than on descent or nobility.
- Some literature:
John Trenchard
John Trenchard (United Kingdom, 1662–1723) was co-author, with Thomas Gordon of Cato's Letters. These newspaper essays condemned tyranny and advanced principles of freedom of conscience and freedom of speech and were a main vehicle for spreading the concepts that had been developed by John Locke.
- Some literature:
- Cato's Letters / John Trenchard & Thomas Gordon, 1720–1723
Charles de Montesquieu
Charles de Montesquieu (France, 1689–1755)
In The Spirit of the Laws, Montesquieu expounded the separation of powers in government and society. In government, Montesquieu encouraged division into the now standard legislative, judicial and executive branches; in society, he perceived a natural organization into king, the people and the aristocracy, with the latter playing a mediating role. "I do not write to censor that which is established in any country whatsoever," Montesquieu disclaimed in the Laws; however, he did pay special attention to what he felt was the positive example of the constitutional system in England, which in spite of its evolution toward a fusion of powers, had moderated the power of the monarch, and divided Parliament along class lines.
Montesquieu's work had a seminal impact on the American and French revolutionaries. Ironically, the least liberal element of his thought—his privileging of the aristocracy—was belied by both revolutions. Montesquieu's system came to fruition in America, a country with no aristocracy; in France, political maneuvering by the aristocracy led to the convocation of the 1789 Estates-General and popular revolt. [2]
- Some literature:
- De l'esprit des lois, 1748 (The Spirit of the Laws) )
- Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences, des arts et des métiers (together with others), 1751–1772 (Encyclopaedia, or Reasoned Dictionary of the Sciences, Arts, and Trades )
Thomas Gordon
Thomas Gordon (United Kingdom, 169?–1750) was co-author, with John Trenchard of Cato's Letters. These newspaper essays condemned tyranny and advanced principles of freedom of conscience and freedom of speech and were a main vehicle for spreading the concepts that had been developed by John Locke.
- Some literature:
- Cato's Letters / John Trenchard & Thomas Gordon, 1720–1723
François Quesnay
François Quesnay (France, 1694–1774)
- Some literature:
- Tableau économique, 1758
- Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences, des arts et des métiers (together with others), 1751-1772 (Encyclopaedia, or Reasoned Dictionary of the Sciences, Arts, and Trades )
Voltaire
Voltaire (France, 1694–1778)
- Some literature:
- Lettres Philosophiques sur les Anglais, 1734 (Philosophical Letters on the English)
- Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences, des arts et des métiers (together with others), 1751-1772 (Encyclopaedia, or Reasoned Dictionary of the Sciences, Arts, and Trades )
- Essai sur l'histoire génerale et sur les moeurs et l'espirit des nations, 1756 (Essay on the Manner and Spirit of Nations and on the Principal Occurrences in History)
- Traité sur la Tolérance à l'occasion de la mort de Jean Calas, 1763 (Treatise on Toleration In Connection with the Death of Jean Calas)
- Dictionnaire Philosophique, 1764 (Philosophical Dictionary)
Jean-Jacques Rousseau
Jean-Jacques Rousseau (Switzerland, 1712–1778)
- Some literature:
- Discourse on Inequality, 1755
- On the Social Contract, 1762
Denis Diderot
Denis Diderot (France, 1713–1784)
- Some literature:
- Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences, des arts et des métiers (together with others), 1751–1772 (Encyclopaedia, or Reasoned Dictionary of the Sciences, Arts, and Trades )
Jean le Rond d'Alembert
Jean le Rond d'Alembert (France, 1717–1783)
- Some literature:
- Encyclopédie, ou dictionnaire raisonné des sciences, des arts et des métiers (together with others), 1751–1772 (Encyclopaedia, or Reasoned Dictionary of the Sciences, Arts, and Trades )
Richard Price
Richard Price (United Kingdom, 1723–1791)
- Some literature:
- Appeal to the Public on the Subject of the National Debt, 1771
- Observations on Reversionary Payments, 1771
- Observations on Civil Liberty and the Justice and Policy of the War with America, 1776
Anders Chydenius
Anders Chydenius (Finland (then a part of the Swedish realm), 1729–1803) His book Den Nationale Winsten (engl. The National Gain) proposed roughly same the ideas as Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations, a decade earlier, including foundations of liberalism and capitalism and (roughly) the invisible hand. He demanded complete economic and individual freedom, including the freedom of religion (although he was a priest), worker's rights to freely move and choose their professions and employers, the freedom of speech and trade and abolitions of all privileges and price and wage controls.
He was also a member of the Swedish four-estates parliament, elected three times as representative of the clergy in the northern and western parts of Finland. In his first parliamentary session, 1765–66, he was very successful as a member of the subcommittee that wrote Sweden's famous Constitutional Law of the Freedom of Printing, Tryckfrihetsförordningen, of 1766. In this law Chydenius combined freedom of the press, and abolishment of the political censorship, with free access for the citizens to most government documents. Chydenius liberal system, where transparency reinforces press freedom, and the right for everyone to print the public document reinforces transparency, has been a fundamental constitutional principle in Sweden ever since, except for the years of royal autocracy 1772-1809. Chydenius model for press freedom and freedom of information was reestablished and strengthened in the Swedish Constitution 1809. It is now the foundation of the present Tryckfrihetsförordningen of 1949, which is one of the fundamental laws of Sweden.
In diluted form, and without the strong constitutional protection of the Swedish free press model, the principle of free access to public documents that originated in Chydenius law of 1766, has in recent decades been spread from Sweden to the Freedom of Information Acts of many countries. This way, Anders Chydenius, has become one of the older liberal thinkers that has most practical influence on politics and public administration of modern western societies.
An edition of Anders Chydenius Complete Works, in Finnish, Swedish and English, is under preparation by the Chydenius Foundation in Finland.
- Some literature:
- Americanska Näfwerbåtar, 1753 (American birchbark canoes)
- Källan Til Rikets Wan-Magt, 1765 (The cause of the weakness of the Kingdom)
- Den Nationnale Winsten, 1765 (The National Gain) )
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (Great Britain, 1723–1790), often considered the founder of modern economics, was a key figure in formulating and advancing economic doctrine of free trade and competition. In his Wealth of Nations Adam Smith outlined the key idea that if the economy is basically left to its own devices, limited and finite resources will be put to ultimately their most efficient use through people acting purely in their self-interest. This concept has been quoted out of context by later economists as the invisible hand of the market.
Smith also advanced property rights and personal civil liberties, including stopping slavery, which today partly form the basic liberal ideology. He was also opposed to stock-holding companies, what today is called a "corporation", because he predicated the self-policing of the free market upon the free association of moral individuals.
- Some literature:
Immanuel Kant
Immanuel Kant (Germany, 1724–1804)
- Some literature:
- Grundlegung zur Metaphysik der Sitten, 1785 (Fundamental Principles of the Metaphysic of Morals )
- Kritik der praktischen Vernunft, 1788 (Critique of Practical Reason )
- Über den Gemeinspruch: Das mag in der Theorie richtig sein, taugt aber nicht für die Praxis, 1793 (On the common saying: this may be true in theory but it does not apply in practice)
- Zum ewigen Frieden, 1795 (Perpetual Peace )
- Metaphysik der Sitten, 1797 (Metaphysics of Morals )
Anne Robert Jacques Turgot
Anne Robert Jacques Turgot (France, 1727–1781)
- Some literature:
- Le Conciliateur, 1754
- Lettre sur la tolérance civile, 1754
- Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses, 1766
- Lettres sur la liberté du commerce des grains, 1770
Joseph Priestley
Joseph Priestley (United Kingdom/United States, 1733–1804)
- Some literature:
- Essay on the First Principles of Government, 1768
- The Present State of Liberty in Great Britain and her Colonies, 1769
- Remarks on Dr Blackstone's Commentaries, 1769
- Observations on Civil Liberty and the Nature and Justice of the War with America, 1772
August Ludwig von Schlözer
August Ludwig von Schlözer (Germany, 1735–1809)
Patrick Henry
Patrick Henry (United States, 1736–1799)
- Some literature:
- Liberty or Death, 1775
Thomas Paine
Thomas Paine (United Kingdom/United States, 1737–1809)
- Some literature:
- Rights of Man, 1791–1792
- Agrarian Justice, 1797
Thomas Jefferson
Thomas Jefferson (United States, 1743–1826) was the third President of the United States and author of the Declaration of Independence. He also wrote Notes on the State of Virginia and the Virginia Statute for Religious Freedom. He was a champion of inalienable individual rights and the separation of church and state. His ideas were repeated in many other liberal revolutions around the world, including the (early) French Revolution.
Marquis de Condorcet
Marquis de Condorcet (France, 1743–1794)
- Some literature:
- Esquisse d'un tableau historique des progrés de l'esprit humain, 1795 (Sketch for a Historical Picture of the Progress of the Human Mind)
Jeremy Bentham
Jeremy Bentham (United Kingdom, 1748–1832) An early advocate of utilitarianism, animal welfare and women's rights. He had many students all around the world, including John Stuart Mill and several political leaders. Bentham demanded economic and individual freedom, including the separation of the state and church, freedom of expression, completely equal rights for women, the end of slavery and colonialism, uniform democracy, the abolition of physical punishment, also on children, the right for divorce, free prices, free trade and no restrictions on interest. Bentham was not a libertarian: he supported inheritance tax, restrictions on monopoly power, pensions, health insurance and other social security, but called for prudence and careful consideration in any such governmental intervention.
Emmanuel Sieyès
Emmanuel Joseph Sieyès (France, 1748–1836) played an important role in the opening years of the French Revolution, drafting the Declaration of the Rights of Man and Citizen, expanding on the theory of national sovereignty, popular sovereignty, and representation implied in his pamphlet What is the Third Estate?.
Antoine Destutt de Tracy
Antoine Destutt de Tracy (1754–1836)
Anne Louise Germaine de Staël
Anne Louise Germaine de Staël (France, 1766–1817)
- Some literature:
- De l'influence des passions sur le bonheur des individus et des nations, 1796
- Des circonstances actuelles qui peuvent terminer la Révolution et des principes qui doivent fonder la république en France, 1798
- Considérations sur les principaux événements de la révolution française, 1813
- Appel aux souverains réunis à Paris pour en obtenir l'abolition de la traite des nègres, 1814
Benjamin Constant
Benjamin Constant (France, 1767–1830)
- Some literature:
- De l'esprit de conquête et l'usurpation (On the spirit of conquest and on usurpation), 1814
- Principes de Politique (Principles of Politics), 1815
- "The Liberty of Ancients Compared with that of Moderns," 1816
Jean-Baptiste Say
Jean-Baptiste Say (France, 1767–1832)
- Some literature:
- Traité d'économie politique (Treatise on Political Economy), 1803
Wilhelm von Humboldt
Wilhelm von Humboldt (Germany, 1767–1835)
- Some literature:
- Ideen zu einem Versuch, die Grenzen der Wirksamkeit des Staats zu bestimmen (On the Limits of State Action), 1792
David Ricardo
David Ricardo (United Kingdom, 1772–1823)
James Mill
James Mill (United Kingdom, 1773–1836)
- Some literature:
- Elements of Political Economy, 1821
Frédéric Bastiat
Frédéric Bastiat (France, 1801–1850)
Claude Frédéric Bastiat was a French classical liberal theorist, political economist, and member of the French assembly. He was notable for developing the important economic concept of opportunity cost.
- Some literature:
- La Loi (The Law), 1849
- Harmonies économiques (Economic Harmonies), 1850
- Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas (What is Seen and What is Not Seen), 1850
Johan Rudolf Thorbecke
The Dutch statesman Johan Rudolf Thorbecke (Netherlands, 1798–1872) was the main theorist of Dutch liberalism in the nineteenth century, outlining a more democratic alternative to the absolute monarchy, the constitutional monarchy. The constitution of 1848 was mainly his work. His main theoretical article specifically labeled as 'liberal' was 'Over het hedendaagsche staatsburgerschap' (On Modern Citizenship) from 1844. He became prime minister in 1849, thus starting numerous fundamental reforms in Dutch politics.
Harriet Martineau
Harriet Martineau (United Kingdom, 1802–1876)
- Some literature:
- Illustrations of Political Economy, 1832–1834
- Theory and Practice of Society in America, 1837
- The Martyr Age of the United States, 1839
Ralph Waldo Emerson
Ralph Waldo Emerson (United States, 1803–1882) was an American philosopher who argued that the basic principles of government were mutable, and that government is required only insofar as people are not self-governing. Proponent of Democracy, and of the idea that a democratic people must have a democratic ethics.
- Some literature:
- Self-Reliance
- Circles
- Politics
- The Nominalist and the Realist
Alexis de Tocqueville
Alexis de Tocqueville (France, 1805–1859)
- Some literature:
- De La Démocratie en Amérique, 1831–1840 (Democracy in America, )
- L'Ancien Régime et la Révolution, 1856
William Lloyd Garrison
William Lloyd Garrison (United States, 1805–1879)
- Some literature:
- Articles advocating abolition of slavery in the newspaper The Liberator, 1831–1866
Friedrich Schiller
Friedrich Schiller (Germany, 1759–1805)
Mill and further, the development of (international) liberalism
- See for the somewhat different development of an American liberalism after World War II the section on American liberal theory. American liberal theorists who also had influence on liberalism outside the United States are included in this section.
John Stuart Mill
John Stuart Mill (United Kingdom, 1806–1873) is one of the first champions of modern "liberalism." As such, his work on political economy and logic helped lay the foundation for advancements in empirical science and public policy based on verifiable improvements. Strongly influenced by Bentham's utilitarianism, he disagrees with Kant's intuitive notion of right and formulates the "highest normative principle" of morals as: Actions are right in proportion as they tend to promote happiness; wrong as they tend to produce the reverse of happiness.
Some consider Mill as the founder of Social liberalism. Although Mill was mainly for free markets, he accepted interventions in the economy, such as a tax on alcohol, if there were sufficient utilitarian grounds. Mill was also a champion of women's rights.
Juan Bautista Alberdi
Juan Bautista Alberdi (Argentina, 1810–1884)
- Some literature:
- Bases y puntos de partida para la organización política de la República Argentina (Bases and Points of Departure for the Political Organization of the Argentine Republic), 1852
- Sistema económico y rentistico de la Confederación Argentina, según su Constitución de 1853 (Economic and rentistic system of the Argentine Confederation, according to its 1853 Constitution), 1854
Henry David Thoreau
Henry David Thoreau (1817–1862)
- Some literature:
Jacob Burckhardt
Jacob Burckhardt (Switzerland, 1818–1897) State as derived from cultural and economic life
- Some literature:
- The Civilization of the Renaissance in Italy
Herbert Spencer
Herbert Spencer (United Kingdom, 1820–1903), philosopher, psychologist, and sociologist, advanced what he called the "Law of equal liberty" and argued against liberal theory promoting more activist government, which he dubbed "a new form of Toryism." He supported a state limited in its duties to the defense of persons and their property. For Spencer, voluntary cooperation was the hallmark of the most vibrant form of society, accommodating the widest diversity of members and the greatest diversity of goals. Spencer's evolutionary approach has been characterized as an extension of Adam Smith's "invisible hand" explanation of economic order; his extensive work on sympathy (in psychology as well as the foundation of ethics, particularly in The Data of Ethics) explicitly carried on Smith's approach in The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Spencer is frequently characterized as a leading Social Darwinist.
- Some literature:
- Social Statics, 1851
- Principles of Ethics, 1879, 1892
- The Man versus the State, 1884
- Essays, Scientific, Political and Speculative, 1892
Thomas Hill Green
Thomas Hill Green (United Kingdom, 1836–1882)
Auberon Herbert
Auberon Herbert (United Kingdom, 1838–1906)
Carl Menger
Carl Menger (Austria, 1840–1921)
- Some literature:
- Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre (Principles of Economics), 1871
- Untersuchungen über die Methode der Sozialwissenschaften und der Politischen Ökonomie insbesondere (Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences: with special reference to economics), 1883
- Irrthumer des Historismus in der deutschen Nationalokonomie (The Errors of Historicism in German Economics), 1884
- Zur Theorie des Kapitals (The Theory of Capital), 1888
William Graham Sumner
William Graham Sumner (United States, 1840–1910)
- Some literature:
- Socialism, 1878
- The Argument Against Protective Tariffs, 1881
- Protective Taxes and Wages, 1883
- The Absurd Effort to Make the World Over, 1883
- State Interference, 1887
- Protectionism: the -ism which teaches that waste makes wealth, 1887
- The Forgotten Man, and Other Essays, 1917
Lester Frank Ward
Lester Frank Ward (United States, 1841–1913) Lester Ward was a botanist, paleontologist, and sociologist. He served as the first president of the American Sociological Association. Ward was a fierce and unrelenting critic of the laissez-faire policies advocated by Herbert Spencer and William Graham Sumner.
- Some literature:
- (1883) Dynamic Sociology: Or Applied social science as based upon statical sociology and the less complex sciences.
- (1893) The Psychic Factors of Civilization, 1893.
- (1903) Pure Sociology. A Treatise on the Origin and Spontaneous Development of Society.
- (1906) Applied Sociology. A Treatise on the Conscious Improvement of Society by Society.
Ward's major works can be found here:
Oliver Wendell Holmes Jr.
Oliver Wendell Holmes Jr. (United States, 1841–1935) was a jurist and writer. He wrote the influential book on legal theory The Common Law, which traced the creation of individual rights from familial rights common under Roman and Feudal law, and presented the "objective" theory of judicial interpretation. Specifically that the standard for intent and culpability should be that of the "reasonable man", and that individuals can be said to objectively intend the reasonable consequences of their actions.
Lujo Brentano
Ludwig Joseph Brentano (Germany, 1844–1931)
Tomáš Masaryk
Tomáš Garrigue Masaryk (Czechoslovakia, 1850–1937)
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (Austria, 1851–1914)
- Some literature:
- Kapital und Kapitalzins (Capital and Interest), in three volumes, 1884, 1889 and 1909
- Die Positive Theorie des Kapitals (The positive theory of capital and its critics), in three volumes, 1895 and 1896
- Zum Abschluss des Marxschen Systems (Karl Marx and the Close of his system),1898
Louis Brandeis
Louis Brandeis (1856–1941)
Thorstein Veblen
Thorstein Veblen (1857–1926) is best known as the author of Theory of the Leisure Class. Veblen was influential to a generation of American liberalism searching for a rational basis for the economy beyond corporate consolidation and "cut throat competition". Veblen's central argument was that individuals require sufficient non-economic time to become educated citizens. He caustically attacked pure material consumption for its own sake, and the idea that utility equalled conspicuous consumption.
John Dewey
John Dewey (United States, 1859–1952)
Friedrich Naumann
Friedrich Naumann (Germany, 1860–1919)
Santeri Alkio
Santeri Alkio (Finland, 1862–1930)
Max Weber
Max Weber (Germany, 1864–1920) was a theorist of state power and the relationship of culture to economics. Argued that there was a moral component to capitalism rooted in "Protestant" values. Weber was along with Friedrich Naumann active in the National Social Union and later in the German Democratic Party.
- Some literature:
- Die protestantische Ethik und der 'Geist' des Kapitalismus,1904 (The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism )
Leonard Hobhouse
Leonard Trelawny Hobhouse (United Kingdom, 1864–1929)
Benedetto Croce
Benedetto Croce (Italy, 1866–1952)
- Some literature:
- Che cosa è il liberalismo, 1943
Walther Rathenau
Walther Rathenau (Germany, 1867–1922)
Sir Leo Chiozza Money
Leo Chiozza Money (Britain, 1870-1944) An Italian-born economic theorist who moved to Britain in the 1890s, where he made his name as a politician, journalist and author. In the early years of the 20th century his views attracted the interest of two future Prime Ministers, David Lloyd George and Winston Churchill. After a spell as Lloyd George's parliamentary private secretary, he was a Government minister in the latter stages of the First World War.
William Beveridge
William Beveridge (United Kingdom, 1879–1963)
- Some literature:
- Full Employment in a Free Society, 1944
- Why I am a liberal, 1945
Ludwig von Mises
Ludwig von Mises (Austria/United States, 1881–1973)
- Some literature:
- Socialism, 1922
- Liberalism, 1927
- Omnipotent Government, 1944
- Human Action, 1949
José Ortega y Gasset
José Ortega y Gasset (Spain, 1883–1955)
- Some literature:
- La rebelión de las masas (The Rebellion of the Masses), 1930
Salvador de Madariaga
Salvador de Madariaga (Spain, 1886–1978). One of the principal authors of the Oxford Manifesto in 1947.
Adolf Berle
Adolf Berle (United States, 1895–1971) was author of The Modern Corporation and Private Property, detailing the importance of differentiating between the management of corporations and the share holders who are the owners. Influential in the theory of New Deal policy.
- Some literature with Gardiner Means:
- The Modern Corporation and Private Property
Wilhelm Röpke
Wilhelm Röpke (Germany, 1899–1966)
- Some literature:
- International Economic Disintegration, 1942
- The Social Crisis of Our Time, 1942
- Civitas Humana, 1944
- International Order and Economic Integration, 1945
- The Solution of the German Problem, 1946
Bertil Ohlin
Bertil Ohlin (Sweden, 1899–1979)
- Some literature:
- Interregional and International Trade, 1933
Friedrich Hayek
Friedrich Hayek (Austria/United Kingdom/United States/Germany, 1899–1992) In Hayek's view, the central role of the state should be to maintain the rule of law, with as little arbitrary intervention as possible. Also a Nobel Prize winner in economics and predicter of the Great Depression like fellow Austrian School economist and mentor Ludwig von Mises.
- Some literature:
- The Road to Serfdom, 1944
- The Constitution of Liberty, 1960
- Law, Legislation and Liberty, in three volumes, 1973, 1976 and 1979
Karl Popper
Karl Raimund Popper (Austria/United Kingdom, 1902–1994) developed the idea of the open society, characterized by respect for a wide variety of opinions and behaviors and a preference for audacious but piecemeal political reform over either conservative stasis or revolutionary utopianism. In his view, all simplistic and grandiose theories of history and society shared a common feature he called historicism, which he traces back to Plato, while the open society mirrors the methodological fallibilism pioneered by Popper in his earlier works on philosophy of science.
- Some literature:
- The Open Society and Its Enemies, 1945
- The Poverty of Historicism, 1961
Alan Paton
Alan Paton (South Africa, 1903–1988) contributed with his book Cry, The beloved country to a clear anti-apartheid stand of South African liberalism. His party, the Liberal Party of South Africa was banned by the apartheid government.
- Some literature:
- Cry, The Beloved Country, 1948
- Ah, but Your Land is Beautiful, 1983
Raymond Aron
Raymond Aron (France, 1905–1983)
- Some literature:
- Essais sur les libertés, 1965
- Démocratie et totalitarisme, 1965
Donald Barkly Molteno
Donald Barkly Molteno (South Africa, 1908–1972), known as Dilizintaba ("He who removes mountains"), was a constitutional lawyer and a parliamentarian but above all, an academic. His work on constitutional law centred on civil rights and his fierce opposition to the segregationalist policies of Apartheid.
Simone de Beauvoir
Simone de Beauvoir (France, 1908–1986) argued in her book The Second Sex that women were treated as legal and social inferiors, and that this was morally untenable. She was influential in the Women's Liberation movement and these arguments also contributed to those about race and racism.
- Some literature:
John Kenneth Galbraith
John Kenneth Galbraith (Canadian-born economist who worked in the United States, 1908–2006)
- Some literature:
- The Affluent Society, 1958
- The Liberal Hour, 1960
Isaiah Berlin
Isaiah Berlin (Latvia/United Kingdom, 1909–1997) is most famous for his attempt to distinguish 'two conceptions of liberty'. Berlin argued that what he called 'positive' and 'negative' liberty were mutually opposing concepts. Positive conceptions assumed that liberty could only be achieved when collective power (in the form of church or state) acted to 'liberate' mankind from its worst aspects. These, Berlin felt, tended towards totalitarianism. Negative conceptions, by contrast, argued that liberty was achieved when individuals were given maximal freedom from external constraints (so long as these did not impinge on the freedom of others to achieve the same condition). Berlin was also a critic of dogmatic Enlightenment rationalism on the grounds that it was unable to accommodate value pluralism.
- Some literature:
- Two Concepts of Liberty, 1958
- Four Essays on Liberty, 1969
- From Hope and Fear Set Free, 1978
Milton Friedman
Milton Friedman (United States, 1912–2006), winner of a Nobel Prize in Economics and a self-identified Classical Liberal and libertarian,[3] was known for the Friedman rule, Friedman's k-percent rule, and the Friedman test.
- Some literature:
- Capitalism and Freedom, 1962
- A Monetary History of the United States, 1963
- Free to Choose, 1980
James Buchanan
James Buchanan (United States, 1919-2013) is known for his economic theories of the political process, which were among the first to take seriously the concept of politicians as rational actors that respond to incentives.
- Some literature:
- The Calculus of Consent / James Buchanan & Gordon Tullock, 1962
- The Limits of Liberty, 1975
- Democracy in Deficit / James Buchanan & Richard E. Wagner, 1977
- The Power to Tax / James Buchanan & Geoffrey Brennan, 1980
- The Reason of Rules / James Buchanan & Geoffrey Brennan, 1985
John Rawls
John Rawls (United States, 1921–2002) is widely considered one of the most important English-language political philosophers of the 20th century. There is general agreement that the publication of his landmark work, A Theory of Justice, led to a revival in the academic study of political philosophy. The importance of this book in contemporary liberal thought and social contract theory is perhaps best described by an early libertarian rival and critic, Robert Nozick, who called it a "work in political and moral philosophy that has not seen its equal since the writings of John Stuart Mill, if then.... Political philosophers must now work within Rawls' theory or explain why not." (Nozick, Anarchy, State, and Utopia, p. 183) Some of Rawls's contributions include the ideas of Justice as Fairness, the original position, reflective equilibrium, overlapping consensus, public reason, and the veil of ignorance. Rawls has the distinction among contemporary political philosophers of being frequently cited by the courts of law in the United States and referred to by practicing politicians in the United Kingdom.
- Some literature:
- A Theory of Justice, 1971
- Political Liberalism, 1996
- The Law of Peoples, 1999
- Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, 2001
Murray Newton Rothbard
Murray Rothbard (United States, 1926–1995) was the originator of modern anarcho-capitalism and an economist and economic historian of the Austrian school. He is widely considered one of the foremost advocates of liberty and freedom in the late 20th century. He was involved with various political movements throughout his life, notably with Ayn Rand and, later, the Libertarian Party of United States. His influence is lasting in the libertarian and anarcho-capitalist movements.
Ayn Rand
Ayn Rand (Russia/United States, 1905–1982) was the founder of the philosophy of Objectivism and a novelist, best known for her philosophical novel Atlas Shrugged which continues to sell tens of thousands of copies every year over half a century later. In contrast with many classical liberal thinkers she made the argument for individual liberty on moral grounds with rational egoism and long-term self-interest. Her shortest summary of this philosophy was:
- Metaphysics: Objective Reality
- Epistemology: Reason
- Ethics: Self-Interest
- Politics: Capitalism
Ralf Dahrendorf
Ralf Dahrendorf (Germany/United Kingdom, 1929–2009 )
- Some literature:
- Die Chancen der Krise: über die Zukunft des Liberalismus, 1983
- Fragmente eines neuen Liberalismus, 1987
Karl-Hermann Flach
The journalist Karl-Hermann Flach (Germany, 1929–1973) was in his book Noch eine Chance für die Liberalen one of the main theorist of the new social liberal principles of the Free Democratic Party (Germany). He places liberalism clearly as the opposite of conservatism and opened the road for a government coalition with the social democrats.
Joseph Raz
Joseph Raz (United Kingdom)
- Some literature:
- The Morality of Freedom
Ronald Dworkin
Ronald Dworkin (United States, 1931–2013 )
Richard Rorty
Richard Rorty (United States, 1931–2007) was one of the leading contemporary philosophers of liberalism. His fundamental claims, among others, are that liberalism is best defined as the attempt to avoid cruelty to others; that liberals need to accept the historical 'irony' that there is no metaphysical justification for their belief that not being cruel is a virtue; that literature plays a crucial role in developing the empathy necessary to promote solidarity (and therefore lack of cruelty) between humans; and that private philosophising and public political discourse are separate practices and should remain so.
Amartya Sen
Amartya Sen (India, 1933– ) is an economist whose early work was based on Kenneth Arrow's General Possibility Theorem, and on the impossibility of both complete pareto optimality and solely procedural based rights. Won Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences for his work on famine, welfare economics and social choice theory. Advocate of rationality as the fundamental safe guard of freedom and justice.
- Some literature:
- Development as Freedom
- The Argumentative Indian
Robert Nozick
Robert Nozick (United States, 1938–2002) was a libertarian (or minarchist). He advocated an unapologetically reductionist political philosophy characterized by meticulous analysis of the moral aspects of each social interaction, and did not shy away from addressing hard philosophical issues such as the original appropriation of property. Nozick is best known for providing the justification of a minimal state by showing that it can be established without any unjust steps.
- Some literature:
Hernando de Soto
The economist Hernando de Soto (Peru, 1941– ) is an advocate of transparency and private property rights, arguing that intransparent government leads to property not being given proper title, and therefore being "dead capital" which cannot be used as the basis of credit. Argues that laws which allocate property to those most able to use them for economic growth, so called "squatter's rights", are an important innovation.
- Some literature:
- The Other Path, 1986.
- The Mystery of Capital, 2000.
Bruce Ackerman
Bruce Ackerman (United States)
- Some literature:
- We, The People
Will Kymlicka
Will Kymlicka (Canada, 1962– ) tries in his philosophy to determine if forms of ethnic or minority nationalism are compatible with liberal-democratic principles of individual freedom, social equality and political democracy. In his book Multicultural Citizenship. A Liberal Theory of Minority Rights he argues that certain "group-differentiated rights" of minority cultures can be consistent with these liberal-democratic principles.
Footnotes
- ↑ Lucien Jaume, "Hobbes and the Philosophical Sources of Liberalism", The Cambridge Companion to Hobbes' Leviathan, 211
- ↑ Bronowski, J and Mazlish, Bruce, The Western Intellectual Tradition, pp. 264–79, especially 273–76.
- ↑ Milton Friedman#Public policy positions